Shadow Open Market Committee

The Shadow Open Market Committee (SOMC) is an independent group of economists, first organized in 1973 by Professors Karl Brunner, from the University of Rochester, and Allan Meltzer, from Carnegie Mellon University, to provide a monetarist alternative to the views on monetary policy and its inflation effects then prevailing at the Federal Reserve and within the economics profession.

At that time, the Fed argued that rising and variable inflation since 1965 was largely attributable to non-monetary forces such as the power of labor unions and oil price shocks, and had little to do with rapid money growth. Based on the principles of monetarism developed earlier by Milton Friedman, the SOMC blamed the Great Inflation squarely on Federal Reserve policies that featured excessive money growth.

The SOMC's principal message that persistent inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon has been widely accepted by central bankers and economists. That framework still forms the basis for the Committee's comments on and criticisms of Federal Reserve policy actions and strategy. Over time, the SOMC has broadened its focus to include issues relating to policies on international trade, exchange rates, and taxes, as well as the regulation of the U.S. banking and financial systems.

The SOMC continues to meet twice per year and maintains an active website that includes an archive of the SOMC's position papers and "Core Beliefs" statement as well as papers of its members. Since 2009, the SOMC has operated in partnership with E21: Economic Policies for the 21st Century.

Founding and early history

Allan Meltzer has described the circumstances that led him, together with Karl Brunner, to organize the Shadow Open Market Committee, and has also chronicled the SOMC’s early history.[1]

When, in 1971, President Richard Nixon adopted wage and price controls in an attempt to reverse the acceleration of inflation, which by then had risen above 4 percent, Brunner and Meltzer wished to form a group of "like-minded economists" to argue against the effectiveness of wage and price controls as a tool for ending inflation and in favor of a gradual reduction in money growth as a preferred alternative. Together with William Wolman, Brunner and Meltzer chose the name "Shadow Open Market Committee," as a reference to both the Federal Open Market Committee, the Federal Reserve's monetary policy making arm, and the Shadow Cabinet as the group of ministers chosen from the opposition party within the U.K. Parliamentary system.[2]

The original SOMC featured twelve members, equal to the number of voting members of the Federal Open Market Committee, chosen from academic institutions, financial institutions, and nonfinancial businesses. Beginning on September 14, 1973, the group met semi-annually in New York City.

John Allan of the New York Times described the first SOMC meeting and policy statement.[3] The Committee urged the Fed to abandon its efforts to fine tune the economy, and focus instead on reducing the rate of money growth from 6 ½ to 5 ½ percent per year, as an initial step towards working inflation down to more acceptable levels.

In 1988, the SOMC moved its meeting location from New York to Washington. Changes in membership gradually occurred, with some former SOMC members leaving to accept high-ranking positions at the Federal Reserve. In this sense, Meltzer points out, the SOMC has functioned somewhat like the U.K. Shadow Cabinet, with its members rotating periodically into official policymaking positions.[2]

Original SOMC member Robert Rasche served as Executive Vice President and Policy Advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis from January 1999 until his retirement in June 2011. Beryl Sprinkel, another original SOMC member, became Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers in 1985. SOMC member Jerry Jordan served as a member of the Council of Economic Advisors in 1981 and 1982 and as President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland from 1992 through 2003. Lee Hoskins served as President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland from 1987 through 1991; William Poole as President of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis from 1998 through 2008; and Charles Plosser as President and of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia from 2006 through 2015.

Anna Schwartz was the longest-serving member of the Shadow Open Market Committee. One of the 12 original members in 1973, Schwartz continued to attend and participate actively in SOMC meetings through 2010.

Subsequent and recent developments

In 2009, the SOMC moved the site of its bi-annual meetings back to New York City.

At its November 2014 meeting, the Committee presented a statement of "Core Beliefs," intended to "help promote its vision and relevance in an era of increasingly complex central banking."[4] The SOMC Core Beliefs relate to the conduct of monetary policy and to the Federal Reserve's role as lender of last resort. They are as follows:

  1. The SOMC takes for granted that U.S. monetary policy will be conducted by the Fed over the foreseeable future.
  2. It is essential that the central bank be independent from the fiscal authorities and accountable to the legislature. In particular, the central bank should eschew policies that allocate credit.
  3. Price stability is the best contribution that monetary policy can make to overall macroeconomic performance and for this reason should be the primary objective of the central bank. "Price stability" should be defined to insure that the inflation rate, on average, is not above 2 percent per year.
  4. Monetary policy should be conducted in a rule-like manner and be somewhat countercyclical with respect to output and employment, as long as price stability over the long run is not compromised. We expect the central bank to announce the policy rule that it follows so that it can be monitored and held accountable.
  5. To provide financial stability, the central bank should promote strong capital buffers.
  6. The SOMC expects the central bank will serve as a lender of last resort. In this role, the central bank should state its lender of last resort policy rules clearly in advance. Such activities should be limited to occasional, temporary, well-collateralized lending to solvent, supervised depository institutions at an appropriate interest rate premium. More expansive lending should be agreed and indemnified in advance by the fiscal authorities.
  7. The SOMC believes that, by following these basic principles, the Fed would create the monetary and financial framework that best facilitates the efficient functioning of free- market, prosperity-creating, institutions in the U.S. economy.

Original members

Past members

Current members

As of April 2019, the following people are listed at the organization.[21]

See also

References

  1. Allan H. Meltzer. "The Shadow Open Market Committee: Origins and Operations" Journal of Financial Services Research vol.18 (December 2000): pp.119-128.
  2. Meltzer (2000) p.121.
  3. John H. Allan. "Monetarists Huddle, Send Central Bankers a Play." New York Times (17 September 1973), pp. 49, 52.
  4. Shadow Open Market Committee. The SOMC and Its Core Beliefs" Position Paper. 3 November 2014.
  5. http://matherhodge.com/tribute/details/382/A-James-Meigs/obituary.html
  6. https://www.nytimes.com/1973/09/17/archives/economists-lose-respect-for-fed-example-of-sarcasm-bankers-most.html
  7. http://econ.msu.edu/people/docs/Rasche%20Obit%20June%202016.pdf
  8. https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/2016-06-17//in-memoriam-robert-h-rasche.pdf
  9. https://www.nytimes.com/1981/07/23/obituaries/wilson-schmidt-dies-world-bank-nominee.html
  10. http://shadowfed.org/committee/
  11. https://www.nytimes.com/2003/09/06/business/h-erich-heinemann-71-writer-economist-and-critic-of-the-fed.html
  12. http://www.federalreservehistory.org/People/DetailView/223
  13. http://crr.bc.edu/about-us/people/affiliated-researchers/rudolph-g-penner/
  14. https://www.aei.org/scholar/rudolph-penner/
  15. http://www.crfb.org/blogs/rudolph-penner-enacting-trump-fiscal-agenda-wont-be-easy
  16. http://www.urban.org/author/rudolph-g-penner
  17. http://aei.pitt.edu/74365/1/BIO_-_EN-MULTI_-_Tumlir.pdf
  18. https://www.wto.org/gatt_docs/English/HAZPDF/1370.pdf
  19. http://view2.fdu.edu/faculty-staff-profile-pages/burton_zwick/
  20. http://www.csmonitor.com/1983/1206/120632.html
  21. http://shadowfed.org/committee/
  22. http://economics.rutgers.edu/component/content/article?id=217:bordo-michael-d
  23. http://www.hoover.org/profiles/michael-d-bordo
  24. http://www.nber.org/people/michael_bordo
  25. https://www0.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/ccalomiris
  26. http://www.politico.com/arena/bio/charles_w_calomiris.html
  27. http://tepper.cmu.edu/our-faculty-and-research/about-our-faculty/faculty-profiles/marvingd/goodfriend-marvin
  28. http://www.cmu.edu/news/experts/alphabetical/goodfriend.html
  29. http://tepper.cmu.edu/-/media/2f348c35818042848ebddd389e592f6e.ashx
  30. https://www.kansascityfed.org/~/media/files/publicat/sympos/2016/econsymposium-goodfriend-paper.pdf
  31. https://www2.bc.edu/~irelandp
  32. http://www.bc.edu/schools/cas/economics/faculty-and-staff/faculty-listing/peter-ireland.html
  33. https://www2.bc.edu/peter-ireland/shortcv.pdf
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.